Copenhagen Conundrum

We are only a week away from the beginning of the highly anticipated global climate summit in Copenhagen.  I recently took part in a mock negotiation session (I represented Mexico), and I can attest to just how difficult it will be to reach any agreement at the summit – even, as has been suggested lately, an agreement in principle without a formally binding treaty.  World leaders recognized as much at the recent Asia Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) meeting, and admitted that it was unrealistic to expect that a legally binding international treaty could be negotiated at Copenhagen.  From the basics of climate science to poverty abatement, the issues that divide the parties are vast.  Those issues have been discussed extensively, so I will instead point out three recent events that may affect the likelihood of a deal:

November 20, 2009: An electronic break-in at the University of East Anglia reveals documents and e-mails that appear to show intent to withhold or manipulate certain data; quickly dubbed “Climategate” by climate skeptics, the leaks are at best embarrassing for prominent climate scientists.

November 25, 2009: President Obama announces that the United States will commit to emissions cuts of 17 percent by 2020 and about 83 percent by 2050; Obama also announced that he will personally attend part of the summit.  The pledges are expected to break a logjam of countries that had been waiting for a United States commitment. 

November 29, 2009: India and China indicate that they may walk out of the negotiations if the developed countries do not agree to the sharing of “green” technology and massive economic transfers for a variety of climate change mitigation and abatement purposes, such as stopping deforestation and forest degradation.

No matter what your position is, the challenges are daunting and the stakes are high.  Whatever happens, the Copenhagen summit will be a fascinating opportunity to observe international diplomacy in the environmental context.

Continue ReadingCopenhagen Conundrum

Should We Abolish Copyright in Academic Journal Articles?

scholarSome years ago, when I was on the Marquette Law Review editorial board, my responsibilities included obtaining a rudimentary copyright release from authors whose articles we had agreed to publish.  In fact, I signed the form myself when I published my Note.  If we did not obtain the release, we would not publish the article.  I presume this is still the Review’s policy, although current members can confirm or deny it, and I also suspect that many journals have a similar procedure.  If the “open access” movement continues to gather steam, however, one can wonder how long this and similar practices will continue.    For example, Professor Steven Shavell recently posted a draft, pre-publication article for public comment arguing that we should abolish copyright for all academic writings.

The open access debate goes well beyond the world of academia, and what follows is only a brief summary.  Many open access advocates support both free online access to works as well as the granting of a license that permits copying and redistribution of the work.  They underscore the broad societal benefits that would flow from broad public access to such information.  Opponents of the movement have argued that true open access is impossible because publishers could not then recover the costs of their work, and that all but a few scholarly journals would cease to exist.  The usual response to this criticism is that the journals could simply charge the authors fees to cover their costs in publishing such works (and, in turn, that the fees would likely be paid by the authors’ university employers).  Perhaps this counterargument is less attractive given the current global economic downturn.

I think the fundamental question is the following: what motivates academic authors to write and publish journal articles? 

Continue ReadingShould We Abolish Copyright in Academic Journal Articles?

Commodifying Environmental Resources

grand canyonMany people value certain environmental resources even if they have never actually visited or “used” those resources.  For example, a person might assign what economists call “nonuse values” to the Grand Canyon, the Great Barrier Reef, or a particular endangered animal species even if she has never hiked the Canyon, gone scuba diving on the Reef, or personally encountered that endangered species.   Some scholars have categorized nonuse values into three types: the “option value” is the value a person places on preserving an environmental resource so that she has the option of using it in the future; the “bequest value” is the value the person places on being able to preserve the resource for the enjoyment of future generations; and the “existence value” is the value the person places on the mere knowledge that the resource exists. 

Consensus has proved elusive on whether and how nonuse values should be considered in cost-benefit analysis of new environmental projects or regulations.  In economic terms, such valuation will have the positive effect of incentivizing people not to destroy the resource.  But economists have struggled to assign actual dollar values suitable for use in such a calculus.  One widely used but controversial method called “contingent valuation” involves the use of surveys to find out what individuals would pay to preserve environmental resources.  Survey results are then averaged and generalized across entire populations.  The design of the survey questions is controversial, and the results are often rigidly contested or even rejected out of hand.  One famous CV study estimated the nonuse harm of the Exxon Valdez disaster at between two and eight billion dollars. 

Quite apart from the raging debate over the validity of contingent valuation, other scholars are waging a separate struggle over whether it is harmful for society to “commodify” or “commoditize” certain things. 

Continue ReadingCommodifying Environmental Resources